Using game theory, real-world scenarios for such situations as pricing competition and product releases (and many more) can be laid out and their outcomes predicted. Companies that use (and stick to) this device to determine the Nash Equilibrium see a huge benefit in their budgeting strategies.(For a quick refresher, see The Basics Of Game Theory.)

Whose Turn Is It?
While sequential games are played by turn, simultaneous games are played with each player making their decision at the same time. With simultaneous games, we no longer use the common introductory method of backward induction. Proponents of game theory often tabulate the different outcomes in what is called a matrix (shown below).

Player one / Player two Left Right
Up (1, 3) (4, 2)
Down (3, 2) (3, 1)

This matrix is referred to as normal form. Player one's choices are shown on the left vertical axis and player two's choices are shown on the top horizontal axis. The payoffs for each player are in their corresponding intersections and are displayed as follows (player one, player two).

The Nash Equilibrium
Nash Equilibrium is an outcome reached that, once achieved, means no player can increase payoff by changing decisions unilaterally. It can also be thought of as "no regrets," in the sense that once a decision is made, the player will have no regrets concerning decisions considering the consequences.

The Nash Equilibrium is reached over time, in most cases. However, once the Nash Equilibrium is reached, it will not be deviated from. After we learn how to find the Nash Equilibrium, take a look at how a unilateral move would affect the situation. Does it make any sense? It shouldn't, and that's why the Nash Equilibrium is described as "no regrets."

Finding a Nash Equilibria
Step One: Determine player one's best response to player two's actions.
When examining the choices that may maximize a player's payout, we must look at how player one should respond to each of the options player two has. An easy way to do this visually is to cover up the choices of player two. Consider the matrix portrayed at the beginning of this article as we apply this method.

Player one / Player two Left Right
Up (1, -) (4, -)
Down (3, -) (3, -)

Player one has two possible choices to play: "up" or "down." Player two also has two choices to play: "left" or "right." In this step of determining Nash Equilibrium, we look at responses to player two's actions. If player two chooses to play "left," we can play "up" with the payoff of one, or play "down" with the payoff of three. Since three is greater than one, we will bold the 3 indicating the option to play "down" here.

If player two chooses to play "right," we can either choose to play 'up' for a payoff of four or play "down" for a playoff of three. Since four is greater than three, we bold the four to indicate the option to play "up" here. The bold outcomes are shown below on the full matrix.

Player one / Player two Left Right
Up (1, 3) (4, 2)
Down (3, 2) (3, 1)

Step Two: Determine player two's best response to player one's actions.
As we did before with the player two payoffs for player one, we will hide the payoffs of player one when determining the best responses for player two. (To learn more about behavioral finance, check out Leading Indicators Of Behavioral Finance.)

Player one / Player two Left Right
Up (-, 3) (-, 2)
Down (-, 2) (-, 1)

Just as when looking at player one, each player has two choices to play. If player one chooses to play "up," we can play "left," with a payoff of three, or "right," with a payoff of two. Since three is greater than two, we bold the three to show the option to play "left" here. If player one chooses to play "down," we can play "left," for a payoff of two, or "right," for a payoff of one. Since two is greater than one, we bold the two indicating the option to play "left" here. The bold outcomes are shown below on the full matrix.

Player one / Player two Left Right
Up (1, 3) (4, 2)
Down (3, 2) (3, 1)

Step Three: Determine which outcomes have both payoffs bold. That particular outcome is the Nash Equilibrium.
Now, we combine the bold options for both players onto the full matrix.

Player one / Player two Left Right
Up (1, 3) (4, 2)
Down (3, 2) (3, 1)

Look for intersections where both payoffs are bold. In this case, we find the intersection of (Down , Left) with the payoff of (3, 2) fits our criteria. This indicates our Nash Equilibrium.

This method of finding Nash Equilibrium is well-suited to finding equilibria in games that are simultaneous since we are looking at how a player would respond independently of how the other acts. This scenario of a simultaneous game is often played out in businesses such as airlines. Below is an example, similar to the game above, of how airline pricing may play out. The payouts are in thousands of dollars. Remember, these are the payouts, not the prices. The method we applied previously is already applied to show where the Nash Equilibrium appears.

Airline one / Airline two Low Price High Price
Low Price (3,000, 3,000) (4,000, 2,000)
High Price (2,000, 4,000) (3,500, 3,500)

Looking at just A1's choices we can see that if A2 chooses to play low price, we choose between Low Price for 3,000 or high price for 2,000. We choose "low," since 3,000>2,000. We do the same thing for A2 playing High Price and see that we play "low" because 4,000>3,500. Conversely, looking just at A2's choices, we can see that if A1 chooses to play low price, we choose between "low price" for 3,000 and "high price" for 2,000. Since 3,000>2,000, we choose the "low price" option here. If A1 plays high price, we can charge a low price for 4,000 or high price for 3,500. Since 4,000>3,500, we choose to play "low price" here.

The Nash Equilibrium is that both airlines will charge a low price (shown when choices for each party are highlighted). If both airlines charged a high price, they would each be better off than they are at the Nash Equilibrium.

So why don't they agree to do this? First off, it's illegal to collude. Second, if this were to occur, a unilateral action on behalf of one airline to charge a low price would be beneficial, resulting in that airline making more money in turn. This logic also shows how the Nash Equilibrium is reached, and why it is not beneficial to deviate from it once it is reached. (For further reading, see our tutorial on Behavioral Finance.)

Multiple Nash Equilibria & How The Nash Equilibrium Plays Out
Generally, there can be more than one equilibrium in a game. However, this usually occurs in games with more complex elements than two choices by two players. In simultaneous games that are repeated over time, one of these multiple equilibria is reached after some trial and error. This scenario of differing choices over time before reaching equilibrium is the most often played out in the business world when two firms are determining prices for very interchangeable products, such as airfare or soda pop.

The Bottom Line
With these advanced methods, more real-world situations can be modeled and solved. The different kinds of Nash Equilibrium we discussed are the most commonly found solutions to real-world modeled games. A working knowledge of Game Theory can help you form a strategy, whether playing a friend playing tic-tac-toe or vying for the largest profits.

Related Articles
  1. Fundamental Analysis

    The Basics Of Game Theory

    Break down and examine the potential consequences of economic/financial scenarios.
  2. Economics

    Understanding Organic Growth

    Organic growth is the increase in a company’s revenue and value due to internal operations.
  3. Investing Basics

    Explaining Options Contracts

    Options contracts grant the owner the right to buy or sell shares of a security in the future at a given price.
  4. Home & Auto

    When Are Rent-to-Own Homes a Good Idea?

    Lease now and pay later can work – for a select few.
  5. Economics

    Explaining Market Penetration

    Market penetration is the measure of how much a good or service is being used within a total potential market.
  6. Economics

    Calculating the Marginal Rate of Substitution

    The marginal rate of substitution determines how much of one good a consumer will give up to obtain extra units of another good.
  7. Economics

    Understanding Cost of Revenue

    The cost of revenue is the total costs a business incurs to manufacture and deliver a product or service.
  8. Fundamental Analysis

    Is India the Next Emerging Markets Superstar?

    With a shift towards manufacturing and services, India could be the next emerging market superstar. Here, we provide a detailed breakdown of its GDP.
  9. Stock Analysis

    5 Reasons Thoratec Corp. Keeps Impressing Investors

    Learn about Thoratec Corporation and its position in its industry. Understand five key factors why the company has impressed investors.
  10. Home & Auto

    4 Areas to Consider Roofing Material Types

    Roofing your home is very important, that’s why you should choose a roof specifically designed to handle your area’s climate.
RELATED TERMS
  1. Principal-Agent Problem

    The principal-agent problem develops when a principal creates ...
  2. Derivative

    A security with a price that is dependent upon or derived from ...
  3. Security

    A financial instrument that represents an ownership position ...
  4. Series 6

    A securities license entitling the holder to register as a limited ...
  5. Discount Bond

    A bond that is issued for less than its par (or face) value, ...
  6. Black Money

    Money earned through any illegal activity controlled by country ...
RELATED FAQS
  1. What is the utility function and how is it calculated?

    In economics, utility function is an important concept that measures preferences over a set of goods and services. Utility ... Read Full Answer >>
  2. How does a forward contract differ from a call option?

    Forward contracts and call options are different financial instruments that allow two parties to purchase or sell assets ... Read Full Answer >>
  3. What does marginal utility tell us about consumer choice?

    In microeconomics, utility represents a way to relate the amount of goods consumed to the amount of happiness or satisfaction ... Read Full Answer >>
  4. What is the difference between JIT (just in time) and CMI (customer managed inventory)?

    Just-in-time (JIT) inventory management focuses solely on the need to replenish inventory only when it is required, reducing ... Read Full Answer >>
  5. What are some examples of Apple and Google's best-selling product lines?

    There are many good examples of product lines in the technology sector from some of the largest companies in the world, such ... Read Full Answer >>
  6. How does a bank determine what my discretionary income is when making a loan decision?

    Discretionary income is the money left over from your gross income each month after taking out taxes and paying for necessities. ... Read Full Answer >>

You May Also Like

Trading Center
×

You are using adblocking software

Want access to all of Investopedia? Add us to your “whitelist”
so you'll never miss a feature!