Using game theory, real-world scenarios for such situations as pricing competition and product releases (and many more) can be laid out and their outcomes predicted. Companies that use (and stick to) this device to determine the Nash Equilibrium see a huge benefit in their budgeting strategies.(For a quick refresher, see The Basics Of Game Theory.)

Whose Turn Is It?
While sequential games are played by turn, simultaneous games are played with each player making their decision at the same time. With simultaneous games, we no longer use the common introductory method of backward induction. Proponents of game theory often tabulate the different outcomes in what is called a matrix (shown below).

Player one / Player two Left Right
Up (1, 3) (4, 2)
Down (3, 2) (3, 1)

This matrix is referred to as normal form. Player one's choices are shown on the left vertical axis and player two's choices are shown on the top horizontal axis. The payoffs for each player are in their corresponding intersections and are displayed as follows (player one, player two).

The Nash Equilibrium
Nash Equilibrium is an outcome reached that, once achieved, means no player can increase payoff by changing decisions unilaterally. It can also be thought of as "no regrets," in the sense that once a decision is made, the player will have no regrets concerning decisions considering the consequences.

The Nash Equilibrium is reached over time, in most cases. However, once the Nash Equilibrium is reached, it will not be deviated from. After we learn how to find the Nash Equilibrium, take a look at how a unilateral move would affect the situation. Does it make any sense? It shouldn't, and that's why the Nash Equilibrium is described as "no regrets."

Finding a Nash Equilibria
Step One: Determine player one's best response to player two's actions.
When examining the choices that may maximize a player's payout, we must look at how player one should respond to each of the options player two has. An easy way to do this visually is to cover up the choices of player two. Consider the matrix portrayed at the beginning of this article as we apply this method.

Player one / Player two Left Right
Up (1, -) (4, -)
Down (3, -) (3, -)

Player one has two possible choices to play: "up" or "down." Player two also has two choices to play: "left" or "right." In this step of determining Nash Equilibrium, we look at responses to player two's actions. If player two chooses to play "left," we can play "up" with the payoff of one, or play "down" with the payoff of three. Since three is greater than one, we will bold the 3 indicating the option to play "down" here.

If player two chooses to play "right," we can either choose to play 'up' for a payoff of four or play "down" for a playoff of three. Since four is greater than three, we bold the four to indicate the option to play "up" here. The bold outcomes are shown below on the full matrix.

Player one / Player two Left Right
Up (1, 3) (4, 2)
Down (3, 2) (3, 1)

Step Two: Determine player two's best response to player one's actions.
As we did before with the player two payoffs for player one, we will hide the payoffs of player one when determining the best responses for player two. (To learn more about behavioral finance, check out Leading Indicators Of Behavioral Finance.)

Player one / Player two Left Right
Up (-, 3) (-, 2)
Down (-, 2) (-, 1)

Just as when looking at player one, each player has two choices to play. If player one chooses to play "up," we can play "left," with a payoff of three, or "right," with a payoff of two. Since three is greater than two, we bold the three to show the option to play "left" here. If player one chooses to play "down," we can play "left," for a payoff of two, or "right," for a payoff of one. Since two is greater than one, we bold the two indicating the option to play "left" here. The bold outcomes are shown below on the full matrix.

Player one / Player two Left Right
Up (1, 3) (4, 2)
Down (3, 2) (3, 1)

Step Three: Determine which outcomes have both payoffs bold. That particular outcome is the Nash Equilibrium.
Now, we combine the bold options for both players onto the full matrix.

Player one / Player two Left Right
Up (1, 3) (4, 2)
Down (3, 2) (3, 1)

Look for intersections where both payoffs are bold. In this case, we find the intersection of (Down , Left) with the payoff of (3, 2) fits our criteria. This indicates our Nash Equilibrium.

This method of finding Nash Equilibrium is well-suited to finding equilibria in games that are simultaneous since we are looking at how a player would respond independently of how the other acts. This scenario of a simultaneous game is often played out in businesses such as airlines. Below is an example, similar to the game above, of how airline pricing may play out. The payouts are in thousands of dollars. Remember, these are the payouts, not the prices. The method we applied previously is already applied to show where the Nash Equilibrium appears.

Airline one / Airline two Low Price High Price
Low Price (3,000, 3,000) (4,000, 2,000)
High Price (2,000, 4,000) (3,500, 3,500)

Looking at just A1's choices we can see that if A2 chooses to play low price, we choose between Low Price for 3,000 or high price for 2,000. We choose "low," since 3,000>2,000. We do the same thing for A2 playing High Price and see that we play "low" because 4,000>3,500. Conversely, looking just at A2's choices, we can see that if A1 chooses to play low price, we choose between "low price" for 3,000 and "high price" for 2,000. Since 3,000>2,000, we choose the "low price" option here. If A1 plays high price, we can charge a low price for 4,000 or high price for 3,500. Since 4,000>3,500, we choose to play "low price" here.

The Nash Equilibrium is that both airlines will charge a low price (shown when choices for each party are highlighted). If both airlines charged a high price, they would each be better off than they are at the Nash Equilibrium.

So why don't they agree to do this? First off, it's illegal to collude. Second, if this were to occur, a unilateral action on behalf of one airline to charge a low price would be beneficial, resulting in that airline making more money in turn. This logic also shows how the Nash Equilibrium is reached, and why it is not beneficial to deviate from it once it is reached. (For further reading, see our tutorial on Behavioral Finance.)

Multiple Nash Equilibria & How The Nash Equilibrium Plays Out
Generally, there can be more than one equilibrium in a game. However, this usually occurs in games with more complex elements than two choices by two players. In simultaneous games that are repeated over time, one of these multiple equilibria is reached after some trial and error. This scenario of differing choices over time before reaching equilibrium is the most often played out in the business world when two firms are determining prices for very interchangeable products, such as airfare or soda pop.

The Bottom Line
With these advanced methods, more real-world situations can be modeled and solved. The different kinds of Nash Equilibrium we discussed are the most commonly found solutions to real-world modeled games. A working knowledge of Game Theory can help you form a strategy, whether playing a friend playing tic-tac-toe or vying for the largest profits.

Related Articles
  1. Fundamental Analysis

    The Basics Of Game Theory

    Break down and examine the potential consequences of economic/financial scenarios.
  2. Savings

    10 Ways To Budget When You’re Broke

    Budgets are some of the best financial tools around – when planned properly and followed faithfully.
  3. Savings

    7 Ways to Trim Fat from Your Spending

    Check out these seven ways to cut the fat from your spending.
  4. Savings

    7 Millionaire Myths

    Here are seven millionaire myths and realities that reveal they don’t quite have it all.
  5. Technical Indicators

    Explaining Autocorrelation

    Autocorrelation is the measure of an internal correlation with a given time series.
  6. Term

    Public Goods & Free Riders

    A public good is an item whose consumption is determined by society, not individual consumers.
  7. Budgeting

    How To Save Money When Moving

    Moving doesn't have to be as expensive as you think. Here are some great ways to save money on moving costs.
  8. Budgeting

    The Hard Way We Pay For Convenience

    Convenience is a luxury. However, any cost-conscious individual should be aware of these ridiculous ways we pay for convenience and how to avoid them.
  9. Budgeting

    How to Cost Effectively Spend on Baby Clothes

    Don't let your baby's wardrobe derail your budget. These top tips help you to save money and spend wisely on baby clothes.
  10. Personal Finance

    College Students are Failing Financial Literacy

    Financial trends among college students are a cause for concern, prompting a renewed emphasis on financial literacy.
  1. How do hedge funds use equity options?

    With the growth in the size and number of hedge funds over the past decade, the interest in how these funds go about generating ... Read Full Answer >>
  2. How do mutual funds split?

    Mutual funds split in the same way that individual stocks split, but less often. Like a stock split, mutual fund splits do ... Read Full Answer >>
  3. Can mutual funds invest in options and futures?

    Mutual funds invest in not only stocks and fixed-income securities but also options and futures. There exists a separate ... Read Full Answer >>
  4. What is the utility function and how is it calculated?

    In economics, utility function is an important concept that measures preferences over a set of goods and services. Utility ... Read Full Answer >>
  5. How does a forward contract differ from a call option?

    Forward contracts and call options are different financial instruments that allow two parties to purchase or sell assets ... Read Full Answer >>
  6. What does marginal utility tell us about consumer choice?

    In microeconomics, utility represents a way to relate the amount of goods consumed to the amount of happiness or satisfaction ... Read Full Answer >>

You May Also Like

Hot Definitions
  1. Purchasing Power

    The value of a currency expressed in terms of the amount of goods or services that one unit of money can buy. Purchasing ...
  2. Real Estate Investment Trust - REIT

    A REIT is a type of security that invests in real estate through property or mortgages and often trades on major exchanges ...
  3. Section 1231 Property

    A tax term relating to depreciable business property that has been held for over a year. Section 1231 property includes buildings, ...
  4. Term Deposit

    A deposit held at a financial institution that has a fixed term, and guarantees return of principal.
  5. Zero-Sum Game

    A situation in which one person’s gain is equivalent to another’s loss, so that the net change in wealth or benefit is zero. ...
  6. Capitalization Rate

    The rate of return on a real estate investment property based on the income that the property is expected to generate.
Trading Center
You are using adblocking software

Want access to all of Investopedia? Add us to your “whitelist”
so you'll never miss a feature!