Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of Unemployment (NAIRU)

What Is the Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of Unemployment?

The non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU) is the specific level of unemployment that is evident in an economy that does not cause inflation to increase. In other words, if unemployment is at the NAIRU level, inflation is constant. NAIRU often represents the equilibrium between the state of the economy and the labor market. 

Key Takeaways

  • The non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU) is the lowest level of unemployment that can occur in the economy before inflation starts to inch higher.
  • When unemployment is at the NAIRU level, inflation is steady; when unemployment rises, inflation decreases; when unemployment drops, inflation increases.
  • With no set formula to determine NAIRU, the Federal Reserve has historically used statistical models to put the NAIRU level somewhere between 5% and 6% unemployment.
  • Assessing the NAIRU level amid its inquiry into inflation and unemployment helps the Federal Reserve in its goal to both achieve maximum employment and price stability.
  • On the downside: NAIRU does not account for the variety of factors that impact unemployment, besides inflation. Also, the historical connection between inflation and unemployment can break down, rendering NAIRU less effective.

How NAIRU Works

Although there is no formula for calculating a NAIRU level, the Federal Reserve has historically used statistical models and estimates that the NAIRU level is somewhere between 5% to 6% unemployment (St. Louis Fed estimates for 2005-2030 are between 4% and 5%). NAIRU plays a role in the Fed's dual mandate objectives of achieving maximum employment and price stability.

For example, the Fed typically targets an inflation rate of 2% as a medium-term level to maintain. If prices rise too quickly due to a strong economy, and it looks like the Fed's inflation target will be exceeded by the inflation rate, the Fed will tighten monetary policy slowing down the economy and inflation.

Understanding NAIRU

According to NAIRU, as unemployment rises over a few years, inflation should decrease. If the economy is performing poorly, inflation tends to fall or subside since businesses can't increase prices due to the lack of consumer demand. If demand for a product decreases, the price of the product falls as fewer consumers want the product resulting in a cut in prices by the business to stimulate demand or buying interest in the product. NAIRU is the level of unemployment that the economy has to rise to before prices begin falling.

Conversely, if unemployment falls below the NAIRU level (the economy is doing well), inflation should increase. If the economy is performing well for many years, companies can raise prices to match demand. Also, the demand for products such as housing, cars, and consumer goods rises, and that demand causes inflationary pressures.

NAIRU represents the lowest level of unemployment that can exist in an economy before inflation begins to rise.

Think of NAIRU as the tipping point between unemployment and rising or falling prices.

How NAIRU Came About

In 1958, New-Zealand–born economist William Phillips wrote a paper titled "The Relation between Unemployment and the Rate of Money Wage Rates" in the United Kingdom. In his paper, Phillips described the supposed inverse relationship between unemployment levels and the rate of inflation. This relationship was referred to as the Phillips curve. However, during the severe recession of 1974 to 1975, inflation and unemployment rates both reached historic levels, and people began to doubt the theoretical basis of the Phillips curve.

Milton Friedman and other critics argued that government macroeconomic policies were being driven by a low unemployment target, which caused the expectations of inflation to change. This led to accelerated inflation rather than reduced unemployment. It was then agreed that government economic policies should not be influenced by unemployment levels below a critical level also known as the “natural rate of unemployment."

NAIRU was first introduced in 1975 as the noninflationary rate of unemployment (NIRU) by Franco Modigliani and Lucas Papademos. It was an improvement on Milton Friedman's concept of the "natural rate of unemployment."

The Correlation Between Unemployment and Inflation

Suppose that the unemployment rate is at 5% and the inflation rate is 2%. Assuming that both of these values remain the same for a period, it can then be said that when unemployment is under 5%, it is natural for an inflation rate of over 2% to correspond with it. Critics cite that it is unlikely for a static rate of unemployment to last for long periods of time because of different levels of factors affecting the workforce and employers (such as natural disasters and political instability) that can quickly shift this equilibrium.

The theory states that if the actual unemployment rate is less than the NAIRU level for a few years, inflationary expectations rise, so the inflation rate tends to increase. If the actual unemployment rate is higher than the NAIRU level, inflationary expectations fall so the inflation rate decreases. If both the unemployment rate and the NAIRU level are equal, the inflation rate remains constant.

NAIRU vs. Natural Unemployment

Natural unemployment, or the natural rate of unemployment, is the minimum unemployment rate resulting from real, or voluntary, economic forces. Natural unemployment reflects the number of people who are unemployed due to the structure of the labor force, such as those replaced by technology or those who lack specific skills to gain employment.

The term full employment is a misnomer since there are always workers looking for employment including college graduates or those displaced by technological advances. In other words, there is always some movement of labor throughout the economy. The movement of labor in and out of employment—whether it's voluntary or not—represents natural unemployment.

NAIRU has to do with the relationship between unemployment and inflation or rising prices. NAIRU is the specific level of unemployment whereby the economy does not cause inflation to increase.

Limitations of Using NAIRU

NAIRU is a study of the historical relationship between unemployment and inflation and represents the specific level of unemployment before prices tend to rise or fall. However, in the real world, the historical correlation between inflation and unemployment can break down.

Also, many factors impact unemployment besides inflation. For example, workers who lack the skills needed to get a job would likely face unemployment, while the workers who have the skills are likely to be employed. One of the challenges lies in estimating the NAIRU level for different groups of workers who have different skill sets.

Why Can Low Unemployment Be Bad for the Economy?

If inflation falls below ideally 5% to 6%, strong consumer demand can cause inflation to rise faster than the Federal Reserve's ideal rate of 2%.

What Is 'Natural Unemployment'?

An economy will never have 100% employment due to the fact that there will always be a number of people who are unemployed due to structural forces such as loss of jobs to technology or a mismatch between their skills and what the job market seeks. Also included are those just joining the labor force, such as new graduates.

What Is the Phillips Curve?

This supposed inverse relationship between unemployment levels and inflation was first described by New-Zealand–born economist William Phillips in 1958.

The Bottom Line

In real life, the correlation between inflation/dropping prices and unemployment can break down. But historically, the phenomenon has held. The level at which the inflation and unemployment are in equilibrium is known as the non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU).

Article Sources
Investopedia requires writers to use primary sources to support their work. These include white papers, government data, original reporting, and interviews with industry experts. We also reference original research from other reputable publishers where appropriate. You can learn more about the standards we follow in producing accurate, unbiased content in our editorial policy.
  1. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. ”What is the lowest level of unemployment that the U.S. economy can sustain?” Accessed Sept. 1, 2020.

  2. Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia. ”NAIRU Estimates from the Board of Governors.” Accessed Sept. 1, 2020.

  3. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. ”Natural Rate of Unemployment (Long-Term).” Accessed Sept. 1, 2020.

  4. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. ”The Federal Reserve's Dual Mandate.” Accessed Sept. 1, 2020.

  5. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. ”What are the Federal Reserve's objectives in conducting monetary policy?” Accessed Sept. 1, 2020.

  6. Wiley Online Library. ”The Relation Between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money Wage Rates in the United Kingdom, 1861–1957.” Accessed Sept. 1, 2020.

  7. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. "Unemployment Rate.” Accessed Sept. 1, 2020.

  8. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. ”Inflation, consumer prices for the United States.” Accessed Sept. 1, 2020.

  9. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco. ”Nobel Views on Inflation and Unemployment.” Accessed Sept. 1, 2020.

  10. The Brookings Institution. ”Targets for Monetary Policy in the Coming Year," Pages 141-142. Accessed Sept. 1, 2020.

  11. The Nobel Prize. ”Press Release - 14 October 1976.” Accessed Sept. 1, 2020.

Open a New Bank Account
×
The offers that appear in this table are from partnerships from which Investopedia receives compensation. This compensation may impact how and where listings appear. Investopedia does not include all offers available in the marketplace.
Sponsor
Name
Description